Preferences and beliefs in a sequential social dilemma: A within-subjects analysis

In empirical analyses of games, preferences and beliefs are typically treated as independent. However, if beliefs and preferences interact, this may have implications for the interpretation of observed behavior. Our sequential social dilemma experiment allows us to separate different interaction cha...

Full description

Autores:
Tipo de recurso:
Fecha de publicación:
2014
Institución:
Universidad del Rosario
Repositorio:
Repositorio EdocUR - U. Rosario
Idioma:
eng
OAI Identifier:
oai:repository.urosario.edu.co:10336/24119
Acceso en línea:
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2014.05.005
https://repository.urosario.edu.co/handle/10336/24119
Palabra clave:
Beliefs
Consensus effect
Experimental economics
Social dilemma
Rights
License
Abierto (Texto Completo)
id EDOCUR2_62461c98841ee82e5cea81478c44c7c5
oai_identifier_str oai:repository.urosario.edu.co:10336/24119
network_acronym_str EDOCUR2
network_name_str Repositorio EdocUR - U. Rosario
repository_id_str
spelling 3597436001ac4de0c-e8f7-42b4-aa62-369a3ca8e179-16504559b-cec3-4f02-9879-3e26fede8d37-141d45aa5-7b5f-4dbf-99b3-dc69c6601aed-12020-05-26T00:08:50Z2020-05-26T00:08:50Z2014In empirical analyses of games, preferences and beliefs are typically treated as independent. However, if beliefs and preferences interact, this may have implications for the interpretation of observed behavior. Our sequential social dilemma experiment allows us to separate different interaction channels. When subjects play both roles in such experiments, a positive correlation between first- and second-mover behavior is frequently reported. We find that the observed correlation primarily originates via an indirect channel, where second-mover decisions influence beliefs through a consensus effect, and the first-mover decision is a best response to these beliefs. Specifically, beliefs about second-mover cooperation are biased toward own second-mover behavior, and most subjects best respond to stated beliefs. However, we also find evidence for a direct, preference-based channel. When first movers know the true probability of second-mover cooperation, subjects' own second moves still have predictive power regarding their first moves. © 2014 Elsevier Inc.application/pdfhttps://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2014.05.0051090247308998256https://repository.urosario.edu.co/handle/10336/24119engAcademic Press Inc.135122Games and Economic BehaviorVol. 87Games and Economic Behavior, ISSN:10902473, 08998256, Vol.87,(2014); pp. 122-135https://www.scopus.com/inward/record.uri?eid=2-s2.0-84901657989&doi=10.1016%2fj.geb.2014.05.005&partnerID=40&md5=831d7c042853622dff95616e201c7e54Abierto (Texto Completo)http://purl.org/coar/access_right/c_abf2instname:Universidad del Rosarioreponame:Repositorio Institucional EdocURBeliefsConsensus effectExperimental economicsSocial dilemmaPreferences and beliefs in a sequential social dilemma: A within-subjects analysisarticleArtículohttp://purl.org/coar/version/c_970fb48d4fbd8a85http://purl.org/coar/resource_type/c_6501Blanco, MarianaEngelmann, DirkKoch, Alexander K.Normann, Hans-TheoORIGINAL1-s2_0-S0899825614000840-main.pdfapplication/pdf724493https://repository.urosario.edu.co/bitstreams/b71add32-53c1-4026-9d08-51d5b13d976d/downloadbbddc1300119f660f3455a8f2abbbc3aMD51TEXT1-s2_0-S0899825614000840-main.pdf.txt1-s2_0-S0899825614000840-main.pdf.txtExtracted texttext/plain69339https://repository.urosario.edu.co/bitstreams/2c9731a1-f348-44bd-ba47-4bdb267bb767/downloadb13bc652e4a8931cf1535c27709d7517MD52THUMBNAIL1-s2_0-S0899825614000840-main.pdf.jpg1-s2_0-S0899825614000840-main.pdf.jpgGenerated Thumbnailimage/jpeg4255https://repository.urosario.edu.co/bitstreams/0d8a7fe3-6a00-4b50-a02c-4e34d8dbfc26/download9d5e92a0c3d424a5e9605aa9a8f2bfdeMD5310336/24119oai:repository.urosario.edu.co:10336/241192022-05-02 07:37:21.59235https://repository.urosario.edu.coRepositorio institucional EdocURedocur@urosario.edu.co
dc.title.spa.fl_str_mv Preferences and beliefs in a sequential social dilemma: A within-subjects analysis
title Preferences and beliefs in a sequential social dilemma: A within-subjects analysis
spellingShingle Preferences and beliefs in a sequential social dilemma: A within-subjects analysis
Beliefs
Consensus effect
Experimental economics
Social dilemma
title_short Preferences and beliefs in a sequential social dilemma: A within-subjects analysis
title_full Preferences and beliefs in a sequential social dilemma: A within-subjects analysis
title_fullStr Preferences and beliefs in a sequential social dilemma: A within-subjects analysis
title_full_unstemmed Preferences and beliefs in a sequential social dilemma: A within-subjects analysis
title_sort Preferences and beliefs in a sequential social dilemma: A within-subjects analysis
dc.subject.keyword.spa.fl_str_mv Beliefs
Consensus effect
Experimental economics
Social dilemma
topic Beliefs
Consensus effect
Experimental economics
Social dilemma
description In empirical analyses of games, preferences and beliefs are typically treated as independent. However, if beliefs and preferences interact, this may have implications for the interpretation of observed behavior. Our sequential social dilemma experiment allows us to separate different interaction channels. When subjects play both roles in such experiments, a positive correlation between first- and second-mover behavior is frequently reported. We find that the observed correlation primarily originates via an indirect channel, where second-mover decisions influence beliefs through a consensus effect, and the first-mover decision is a best response to these beliefs. Specifically, beliefs about second-mover cooperation are biased toward own second-mover behavior, and most subjects best respond to stated beliefs. However, we also find evidence for a direct, preference-based channel. When first movers know the true probability of second-mover cooperation, subjects' own second moves still have predictive power regarding their first moves. © 2014 Elsevier Inc.
publishDate 2014
dc.date.created.spa.fl_str_mv 2014
dc.date.accessioned.none.fl_str_mv 2020-05-26T00:08:50Z
dc.date.available.none.fl_str_mv 2020-05-26T00:08:50Z
dc.type.eng.fl_str_mv article
dc.type.coarversion.fl_str_mv http://purl.org/coar/version/c_970fb48d4fbd8a85
dc.type.coar.fl_str_mv http://purl.org/coar/resource_type/c_6501
dc.type.spa.spa.fl_str_mv Artículo
dc.identifier.doi.none.fl_str_mv https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2014.05.005
dc.identifier.issn.none.fl_str_mv 10902473
08998256
dc.identifier.uri.none.fl_str_mv https://repository.urosario.edu.co/handle/10336/24119
url https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2014.05.005
https://repository.urosario.edu.co/handle/10336/24119
identifier_str_mv 10902473
08998256
dc.language.iso.spa.fl_str_mv eng
language eng
dc.relation.citationEndPage.none.fl_str_mv 135
dc.relation.citationStartPage.none.fl_str_mv 122
dc.relation.citationTitle.none.fl_str_mv Games and Economic Behavior
dc.relation.citationVolume.none.fl_str_mv Vol. 87
dc.relation.ispartof.spa.fl_str_mv Games and Economic Behavior, ISSN:10902473, 08998256, Vol.87,(2014); pp. 122-135
dc.relation.uri.spa.fl_str_mv https://www.scopus.com/inward/record.uri?eid=2-s2.0-84901657989&doi=10.1016%2fj.geb.2014.05.005&partnerID=40&md5=831d7c042853622dff95616e201c7e54
dc.rights.coar.fl_str_mv http://purl.org/coar/access_right/c_abf2
dc.rights.acceso.spa.fl_str_mv Abierto (Texto Completo)
rights_invalid_str_mv Abierto (Texto Completo)
http://purl.org/coar/access_right/c_abf2
dc.format.mimetype.none.fl_str_mv application/pdf
dc.publisher.spa.fl_str_mv Academic Press Inc.
institution Universidad del Rosario
dc.source.instname.spa.fl_str_mv instname:Universidad del Rosario
dc.source.reponame.spa.fl_str_mv reponame:Repositorio Institucional EdocUR
bitstream.url.fl_str_mv https://repository.urosario.edu.co/bitstreams/b71add32-53c1-4026-9d08-51d5b13d976d/download
https://repository.urosario.edu.co/bitstreams/2c9731a1-f348-44bd-ba47-4bdb267bb767/download
https://repository.urosario.edu.co/bitstreams/0d8a7fe3-6a00-4b50-a02c-4e34d8dbfc26/download
bitstream.checksum.fl_str_mv bbddc1300119f660f3455a8f2abbbc3a
b13bc652e4a8931cf1535c27709d7517
9d5e92a0c3d424a5e9605aa9a8f2bfde
bitstream.checksumAlgorithm.fl_str_mv MD5
MD5
MD5
repository.name.fl_str_mv Repositorio institucional EdocUR
repository.mail.fl_str_mv edocur@urosario.edu.co
_version_ 1831928316721889280