Rebellion, Repression and Welfare
I develop a dynamic model of social conflict whereby manifest grievances of the poor generate the incentive of taking over political power violently. Rebellion can be an equilibrium outcome depending on the level of preexisting inequality between the poor and the ruling elite, the relative military...
- Autores:
- Tipo de recurso:
- Fecha de publicación:
- 2011
- Institución:
- Universidad del Rosario
- Repositorio:
- Repositorio EdocUR - U. Rosario
- Idioma:
- eng
- OAI Identifier:
- oai:repository.urosario.edu.co:10336/23835
- Acceso en línea:
- https://doi.org/10.1080/10242694.2011.594598
https://repository.urosario.edu.co/handle/10336/23835
- Palabra clave:
- Inequality
Markov perfect equilibrium
Rebellion
Repression
- Rights
- License
- Abierto (Texto Completo)
id |
EDOCUR2_131d42694094cbcea19b4739a03d4d7a |
---|---|
oai_identifier_str |
oai:repository.urosario.edu.co:10336/23835 |
network_acronym_str |
EDOCUR2 |
network_name_str |
Repositorio EdocUR - U. Rosario |
repository_id_str |
|
spelling |
799502236002020-05-26T00:05:52Z2020-05-26T00:05:52Z2011I develop a dynamic model of social conflict whereby manifest grievances of the poor generate the incentive of taking over political power violently. Rebellion can be an equilibrium outcome depending on the level of preexisting inequality between the poor and the ruling elite, the relative military capabilities of the two groups and the destructiveness of conflict. Once a technology of repression is introduced, widespread fear reduces the parameter space for which rebellion is an equilibrium outcome. However, I show that repression-driven peace comes at a cost as it produces a welfare loss to society. © 2011 Copyright Taylor and Francis Group, LLC.application/pdfhttps://doi.org/10.1080/10242694.2011.5945981476826710242694https://repository.urosario.edu.co/handle/10336/23835eng579No. 5563Defence and Peace EconomicsVol. 22Defence and Peace Economics, ISSN:14768267, 10242694, Vol.22, No.5 (2011); pp. 563-579https://www.scopus.com/inward/record.uri?eid=2-s2.0-84859074430&doi=10.1080%2f10242694.2011.594598&partnerID=40&md5=ce99d7bbe2dc28760530e496bb14962aAbierto (Texto Completo)http://purl.org/coar/access_right/c_abf2instname:Universidad del Rosarioreponame:Repositorio Institucional EdocURInequalityMarkov perfect equilibriumRebellionRepressionRebellion, Repression and WelfarearticleArtículohttp://purl.org/coar/version/c_970fb48d4fbd8a85http://purl.org/coar/resource_type/c_6501Vargas Duque, Juan Fernando10336/23835oai:repository.urosario.edu.co:10336/238352022-05-02 07:37:17.556249https://repository.urosario.edu.coRepositorio institucional EdocURedocur@urosario.edu.co |
dc.title.spa.fl_str_mv |
Rebellion, Repression and Welfare |
title |
Rebellion, Repression and Welfare |
spellingShingle |
Rebellion, Repression and Welfare Inequality Markov perfect equilibrium Rebellion Repression |
title_short |
Rebellion, Repression and Welfare |
title_full |
Rebellion, Repression and Welfare |
title_fullStr |
Rebellion, Repression and Welfare |
title_full_unstemmed |
Rebellion, Repression and Welfare |
title_sort |
Rebellion, Repression and Welfare |
dc.subject.keyword.spa.fl_str_mv |
Inequality Markov perfect equilibrium Rebellion Repression |
topic |
Inequality Markov perfect equilibrium Rebellion Repression |
description |
I develop a dynamic model of social conflict whereby manifest grievances of the poor generate the incentive of taking over political power violently. Rebellion can be an equilibrium outcome depending on the level of preexisting inequality between the poor and the ruling elite, the relative military capabilities of the two groups and the destructiveness of conflict. Once a technology of repression is introduced, widespread fear reduces the parameter space for which rebellion is an equilibrium outcome. However, I show that repression-driven peace comes at a cost as it produces a welfare loss to society. © 2011 Copyright Taylor and Francis Group, LLC. |
publishDate |
2011 |
dc.date.created.spa.fl_str_mv |
2011 |
dc.date.accessioned.none.fl_str_mv |
2020-05-26T00:05:52Z |
dc.date.available.none.fl_str_mv |
2020-05-26T00:05:52Z |
dc.type.eng.fl_str_mv |
article |
dc.type.coarversion.fl_str_mv |
http://purl.org/coar/version/c_970fb48d4fbd8a85 |
dc.type.coar.fl_str_mv |
http://purl.org/coar/resource_type/c_6501 |
dc.type.spa.spa.fl_str_mv |
Artículo |
dc.identifier.doi.none.fl_str_mv |
https://doi.org/10.1080/10242694.2011.594598 |
dc.identifier.issn.none.fl_str_mv |
14768267 10242694 |
dc.identifier.uri.none.fl_str_mv |
https://repository.urosario.edu.co/handle/10336/23835 |
url |
https://doi.org/10.1080/10242694.2011.594598 https://repository.urosario.edu.co/handle/10336/23835 |
identifier_str_mv |
14768267 10242694 |
dc.language.iso.spa.fl_str_mv |
eng |
language |
eng |
dc.relation.citationEndPage.none.fl_str_mv |
579 |
dc.relation.citationIssue.none.fl_str_mv |
No. 5 |
dc.relation.citationStartPage.none.fl_str_mv |
563 |
dc.relation.citationTitle.none.fl_str_mv |
Defence and Peace Economics |
dc.relation.citationVolume.none.fl_str_mv |
Vol. 22 |
dc.relation.ispartof.spa.fl_str_mv |
Defence and Peace Economics, ISSN:14768267, 10242694, Vol.22, No.5 (2011); pp. 563-579 |
dc.relation.uri.spa.fl_str_mv |
https://www.scopus.com/inward/record.uri?eid=2-s2.0-84859074430&doi=10.1080%2f10242694.2011.594598&partnerID=40&md5=ce99d7bbe2dc28760530e496bb14962a |
dc.rights.coar.fl_str_mv |
http://purl.org/coar/access_right/c_abf2 |
dc.rights.acceso.spa.fl_str_mv |
Abierto (Texto Completo) |
rights_invalid_str_mv |
Abierto (Texto Completo) http://purl.org/coar/access_right/c_abf2 |
dc.format.mimetype.none.fl_str_mv |
application/pdf |
institution |
Universidad del Rosario |
dc.source.instname.spa.fl_str_mv |
instname:Universidad del Rosario |
dc.source.reponame.spa.fl_str_mv |
reponame:Repositorio Institucional EdocUR |
repository.name.fl_str_mv |
Repositorio institucional EdocUR |
repository.mail.fl_str_mv |
edocur@urosario.edu.co |
_version_ |
1818106400314753024 |